The
Policy Dimensions of FDI
An analysis is now
made of the different FDI policy dimensions in which PIs are made to be
implemented by host
countries. It is important to note here that governments of developing
countries choose PIs –
generalized as incentives – to
attract FDI in relation to their overall
economic development
goals. Thus, different dimensions of incentives can be depicted. First,
incentives can be
either general or specific (with a discretionary perspective). A
second
dimension is the
durability of incentives. Indeed, according to the host country’s priorities,
incentives could be
either permanent or temporal. However, pragmatically speaking,
PIs related
to incentives need to
change in duration so as to encourage the kinds of FDI and industrial
specialization the
country desires. And therefore it is useful to think of these PIs as windows of
opportunity which
open and close. Another dimension exists at the geographic – or spatial –
level since IP
policies can target FDI either at a local, national level or regional
level. Local
incentives can be
used to promote specific regions of a country that are poorer or in greater
need development.
Further, incentives can be used to attract foreign investors to the whole economy or only to certain sectors
or subsectors, according again to the specific needs of the country. In the past, this has
carried the rubric ‘negative’ or ‘positive’ lists which cordoned off strategic sectors of the
economy to foreign investors and reserved others for national firm.26 Finally, at the firm level,
incentives can focus either on all FDI, or only on specific investors.
These dimensions are depicted in
figure 4, A Framework for Operationalizing FDI Policy Dimensions and Instruments.
To say that policy
craft – creating policy coherence out of the conflicting demands from modal
neutrality, market
contestability, as well as scaling and measuring the factors and variables
which must be
considered in policy research and analysis – is a challenge, is an understatement.
This paper makes
early reference to the growing importance of investment and business climate
benchmarking as a
guide to policy-making. However, econometrically, as every factor or
variable (or their
combinations) has its own FDI inflow- and stock-elasticity, IPAs and policy
makers with limited
resources should concentrate their policy craft on those FDI factors and
variables with the
highest FDI-elasticities . In rank order, these are: (i)
growth-competitiveness,
which combines macroeconomic and technology variables, with an FDI inflow elasticity of
0.63; (ii) economic freedom, combining government intervention, property rights, wages/prices
and regulation variables, with an FDI inflow-elasticity of 0.56; (iii) taxation and regulation with
an FDI inflow-elasticity of -0.50; (iv) quality of telecommunication services with FDI
inflow-elasticity of -0.28;28 and
(v) labour market regulation with FDI inflow-elasticity of -0.26.
Furthermore, these elasticities have short- medium- and long-term adjustment
rates.
This approach begins
to lay out the choices available to policy makers in making viable PIs in a
systematic manner
based on rigorous analysis. Hence, from a fourth-generation IP perspective, a focus on the
macroeconomic environment stability and technology policies to increase the
rates of innovation and
transfer by PIs that facilitate licensing and franchising, for example, would
be needed. In a similar
vein, harmonizing taxation regulation across regional space would be a viable policy.
All these elements
and issues in figure 4 reflect the need for sequencing and switching PIs and
incentives, both in
space and time. In other words, while FDI policy-making is increasingly more complex and diverse,
host governments, according to their development needs, have to adapt to the MNEs dynamic
activities by sequencing and switching (in a predictable manner) their FDI PIs. Moreover, these
different policy dimensions also indicate the importance for host
governments to create
different levels of policies: the meta- or supra-national level, the macro or national level, the
meso or regional and cluster level, the micro or industrial sector and
subsector level and the firm
level of organizational strategy and competitiveness . The complexity of FDI
host policy-making is obvious but the policy dimensions have to be chosen and established in
harmony with the general development goals set up by the government.
Whereas industrialized
countries typically utilize financial incentives, such as grants, developing countries usually use
fiscal incentives, such as reductions in the base rate of corporate income tax, tax holidays and
import-duty exemptions and drawbacks (Oman, 2000). Incentives are widely used to
attract MNEs and thus create a climate of policy competition for FDI. Fiscal incentives might be
successful for attracting MNEs, but incentives-based competition also creates some
problems. Indeed, the first problem of incentives is that they represent
opportunity cost of resources to
host governments. Secondly, there can be a significant lack of transparency regarding incentives,
which leaves space for corruption and other kinds of rent-seeking behaviour. Finally,
given the dimension choices in figure 4, incentives also provoke market distortions. Among
them, the major ones are the fact that incentives tend to favour large corporate investors
to the detriment of small ones, as well as foreign over the domestic firms because of their
lower risk profile and higher bargaining power. The distortion would tend to disappear (over time)
in countries adopting fourth generation of IP, as they would treat foreign and domestic firms equally with regard
to incentives.
No comments:
Post a Comment