Dr.DEBESH BHOWMIK

Dr.DEBESH BHOWMIK

Thursday, 7 November 2013

Reforming Energy Subsidies



Reforming Energy Subsidies

---IMF


Subsidies are intended to protect consumers by keeping prices low. But they also come at a high cost.
Subsidies are expensive for governments—and therefore taxpayers—to finance and can hinder governments’ efforts to reduce budget deficits. They also compete with other priority public spending on roads, schools, and healthcare.
All consumers—both rich and poor—benefit from subsidies by paying lower prices. Governments could get more “bang for their buck” by removing or reducing subsidies and targeting the money directly to programs that help only the poor.
Subsidies encourage excessive energy consumption, which accelerates the depletion of natural resources. They also reduce the incentive for investment in other forms of cleaner energy.
Measuring subsidies
Producer subsidies often arise because energy producers—usually state-owned enterprises (SOEs)—are inefficient and have high costs of production. In the electricity sector, producer subsidies can also arise because of non-payment of bills and power distribution losses which weaken the revenues of SOEs.
Consumer subsidies can include two components: a pre-tax subsidy and a tax subsidy.
Pre-tax subsidies exist when energy consumers pay prices that are below the costs incurred to supply them with this energy. Taking gasoline as an example—and remembering it is internationally traded, the pre-tax subsidy is simply the international price of gasoline less the final price paid by consumers at the pump.
Tax subsidies exist if taxes for energy are below their efficient level. This has two components. First, energy should be taxed the same way as any other consumer products. If energy taxes are lower than this, there is a tax subsidy. Second, some energy products contribute to pollution and global warming—efficient taxation requires that the price of energy should reflect these adverse effects on society. In most countries, taxes on energy fall far short of this, implying the full costs of consuming energy are not reflected in its price, as it should when energy is priced right.
Post-tax subsidies are the sum of pre-tax and tax subsidies. Post-tax subsidies are four times larger than pre-tax subsidies, and advanced economies account for 40 percent of post-tax subsidies. But as a share of gross domestic product, post-tax subsidies are roughly eight times larger in the Middle East and North African region than in advanced economies.



Reform efforts

In 2009, the Group of 20 advanced and emerging market economies called for a phase out of inefficient fossil fuel subsidies in all countries, and reaffirmed this again in 2012.
Despite the potential gains, many countries have had difficulty reforming subsidies. When reforms are made, prices increase, and this has often led to widespread public protests.
The absence of public support for subsidy reform is in part due to a lack of confidence in the ability of governments to shift the resulting budgetary savings to programs that would compensate the poor and middle class for the higher energy prices they face.
This problem is particularly challenging in oil-exporting countries, where subsidies are seen as a mechanism to distribute the benefits of natural resource endowments to their populations and where the capacity to administer targeted social programs is typically limited.
Governments are also often concerned that higher energy prices will contribute to a higher rate of inflation and adversely affect their competitiveness. Subsidy reform can also be complex when it includes trying to reduce inefficiencies and production costs, as is often the case for the electricity sector.

A plan for reform

While there is no single recipe for successful subsidy reform, country experiences suggest that the following ingredients are needed:
  • a comprehensive energy sector reform plan with clear long-term objectives with an analysis of the impact of reforms;
  • transparent and extensive communication and consultation with stakeholders, including information on the size of subsidies and how they affect the government’s budget;
  • price increases that are phased-in over time;
  • improving the efficiency in state-owned enterprises to reduce producer subsidies;
  • measures to protect the poor through targeted cash or near-cash transfers or, if this option is not feasible, a focus on existing targeted programs that can be expanded quickly; and
  • institutional reforms that depoliticize energy pricing, such as the introduction of automatic pricing mechanisms.

Wednesday, 6 November 2013

ADB on Inequality






Inequality in the Asia and Pacific Region: 12 Things to Know



Despite Asia's remarkable economic progress over the last decades, inequality remains a problem in the region.
  1. Inclusive growth, defined as economic growth with equality of opportunity, is one of the three strategic objectives of ADB.
    Source: ADB document Framework of Inclusive Growth Indicators 2013
  1. From 1990 to 2010, Asia and the Pacific has halved extreme poverty and seen an annual rise in average per capita income of nearly 6%. However, data shows a worsening of the rich/poor gap in many economies.
    Source: ADB document Framework of Inclusive Growth Indicators 2013
  1. The best improvements have been seen in poverty reduction (at the $2 a day measure), under-five mortality rates, and in average years of schooling.
    Source: ADB document Framework of Inclusive Growth Indicators 2013
  1. Countries with high Gini coefficients (inequality measure) where the poorest quintile of the population had the lowest shares of national income or consumption included the People's Republic of China, Malaysia and several Pacific Islands.
    Source: ADB publication Key Indicators for Asia and the Pacific 2013
  1. Child mortality has been cut in half over the last two decades but progress on reducing the number of underweight children has been poor.
    Source: ADB document Framework of Inclusive Growth Indicators 2013
  1. Many workers earn too little to lift their families out of poverty and the number without formal work exceeded 40% of the total employed in 18 economies, with the proportion being over 80% in India and Bangladesh.
    Source: ADB publication Key Indicators for Asia and the Pacific 2013
  1. Electricity consumption over the last two decades has more than tripled but wide disparities still exist between rural and urban areas, while cellular phone subscriptions have grown in all economies.
    Source: ADB document Framework of Inclusive Growth Indicators 2013
  1. The region has seen an increase in the average number of years children stay in school and most economies have improved gender parity in primary education. However, gender parity in the labor force has deteriorated.
    Source: ADB document Framework of Inclusive Growth Indicators 2013
  1. The People's Republic of China and 15 other economies had youth (aged 15-24) literacy rates of at least 99% but 11 economies had rates below 95%, including Pakistan with 71%.
    Source: ADB publication Key Indicators for Asia and the Pacific 2013
  1. Social security spending on health as a percentage of government expenditure has risen but there are sharp disparities amongst countries.
    Source: ADB document Framework of Inclusive Growth Indicators 2013
  1. Migrant workers' remittances are now a major source of foreign exchange across Asia and the Pacific region.
    Source: ADB publication Key Indicators for Asia and the Pacific 2013
  1. Migrant workers' remittances is now a major source of foreign exchange across Asia and the Pacific region.
    Source: ADB publication Key Indicators for Asia and the Pacific 2013

Thursday, 31 October 2013

BEHAVIOUR OF GOLD PRICE

BEHAVIOUR OF GOLD PRICE

-Dr.Debesh Bhowmik

The steady gold price was observed in the gold standard at 35$/ounce till 1971.After the breakdown of Brettonwoods , the gold price steadily increased  upto 850$/ounce within 1979,then inflation started to fall down which induced falling gold price which converged around 300-500 $/ounce till 2004 but within 2008  ,it reached to 950$/ounce through Katrina agreement and credit crunch .From January 2005 to January 2010,gold price again steadily stepped up to more than 1800$/ounce but during 2013 it again started to behave volatile with falling trend.


The future forecast of gold price is observed as upward trend reaching 3400$/ounce within 2016.

Saturday, 26 October 2013

THE CARBON MARKET AND CARBON FINANCING




The Carbon Market and Carbon Financing
----Dr.Debesh Bhowmik



What is Emissions Trading?

‘Carbon trading’, or ‘emissions trading’, takes place when there is sale and purchase of:[i] ‘permits’ or ‘allowances’ to emit greenhouse gases; or[ii] ‘certificates’ that prove a certain reduction in emissions from a particular activity beyond what would otherwise have been the case (i.e. ‘business as usual’ emissions); or[iii] certificates that indicate a certain amount of actual emissions have been ‘offset’ somewhere else, through for example, carbon sequestration.

Usually, each permit, allowance or certificate is a document, often electronic, representing one tonne (1,000 kg) of carbon dioxide equivalent (‘CO2e’) that was emitted, or not emitted below business-as-usual projections for emissions. The term CO2e means that greenhouse gases other than carbon dioxide are converted to tones of CO2e, based on their relative contribution to global warming. This provides for a single, uniform means of measuring emissions reductionsfor multiple greenhouse gases.

What is the Carbon Market?

Transactions for the sale of emissions permits, reductions or offsets together comprise the ‘carbon market’, which has grown exponentially since the entry into force of the Kyoto Protocol in 2002. In fact the term ‘carbon market’ is not entirely accurate: because carbon dioxide is only one of several greenhouse gases that can be ‘traded’; and because there is not a single, unified international market for emissions reduction purchases. Rather, there are various markets in operation around the world, which can be classified as either regulated or unregulated markets and which interact with one another in different ways.

‘Regulated markets’ are emissions trading schemes set up under domestic or international law to provide a means for specified actors (often large industrial or power companies) to meet emissions reduction targets. Key examples include the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme and the New South Wales and Australian Capital Territory Greenhouse Gas Abatement Schemes. Such schemes usually provide that the actors can trade emissions reduction allowances among themselves (i.e. one company that has exceeded its emissions reduction target could buy surplus allowances from another company that has emitted less greenhouse gases than its specified target). Or it may provide for a company with an emissions reduction target to buy offsets or credits for emissions reductions achieved in some other activity, then apply these

toward meeting its own target.

‘Unregulated markets’ arise where there are private agreements to trade or offset emissions or emissions reductions among actors who may not be legally bound to meet an emissions reduction target, but who have decided to take action anyway. Sometimes these are one-off, single agreements and sometimes they are part of wider voluntary schemes, each with its own procedures. WWF recently published a guide that explains the voluntary carbon market and compares some of the big voluntary schemes in existence.

What is the Size of the Market?

In light of the fragmented nature of the market, it is difficult to describe precisely its current and

projected size. Research indicates that the entire global market was worth more than US$30 billion in 2006, three times its value in the previous year , to then over US$60 billion in 2007. The biggest part of the market is the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme. There are no clear figures on Indigenous involvement in the global market.



Generating Tradable Credits

Types of Activities that Generate Tradable Credits

Key greenhouse gas mitigation activities that can generate credits or offsets for sale include energy efficiency, renewable energy and land use and forestry activities. Other kinds of activities that may also generate credits but which are not addressed here include the management of methane released from landfill or waste sites or by livestock, and the substitution of oil, coal or diesel with gas, biofuels or other renewable energy for use in transportation or industrial processes. The first three are described in more detail below.

Energy Efficiency Projects

‘Energy efficiency’ involves reducing the amount of energy used to operate a product or to carry out a process, without reducing the quality or level of service. You might choose, for example,

a car that needs less fuel to travel the same distance at the same speed as another that uses more fuel. Related to that, energy conservation may involve reducing the demand or need for energy. Energy efficiency activities can be undertaken in industry, agriculture, electricity generation, transportation or households among others – really in any activity where an opportunity exists to use energy in a more efficient way. One example of an energy efficiency project that could attract carbon financing would be the replacement of old, inefficient light bulbs throughout a community with new light bulbs that use less electricity to give the same amount of light.

Renewable Energy Projects

‘Renewable’ energy can be used to provide electricity, heating or fuel for transportation similar

to the way we use fossil fuels for these purposes. Such sources are called ‘renewable’ because, unlike oil, gas and coal, there is not a finite amount of them in the earth. Key renewable sources include wood, waste decomposition, geothermal activity, wind and solar energy. The use of renewable sources for generating energy usually involves lower emissions of greenhouse gasesthan the use of fossil fuels does. An example of a renewable energy project would be to switch from using a diesel generator for providing electricity, to using solar panels to provide electricity.

Land Use and Forestry Projects

As plants and trees act as carbon sinks, various ‘land use and forestry’ activities can lead to a reduction in atmospheric greenhouse gas emissions. In particular, reducing the rate of, or avoiding entirely, land clearing or deforestation is one such way because these activities release carbon dioxide into the atmosphere. Another is by planting new trees to absorb more carbon dioxide. Other land management practices may also be undertaken - such as carrying out controlled burning in the early part of the dry season to prevent more frequent and intense bush fires later in the dry season. Controlled burning may not only help to reduce emissions, but may also help to control pests and weeds, maintain traditional Indigenous land management

practices and provide for employment and training opportunities.

What is Involved in Generating Tradable Credits?

Who may buy and sell credits or offsets, and the particular procedures involved in generating

credits for sale, vary considerably from one regulatory scheme to the next and from one transaction to the next within the unregulated market. Often times, the purchase of credits or offsets will take place by way of a legal agreement or contract between two or more ‘parties’. The terms of the agreement may be decided upon by the parties, however, a regulatory scheme under which a sale takes place may also require that certain terms be included in the agreement. Here are some requirements that are common in the purchase or financing of emissions reductions.



1) Additionality:

Generally speaking, tradable emissions reductions must occur in addition to any reductions that would have occurred in a business-as-usual situation - i.e. they must be emissions reductions that would not have occurred without the funded activity or project. This requirement is called ‘additionality’. For example, if a community has already replaced diesel generators with solar panels for providing hot water that uses less greenhouse gases, it may not be able to sell credits or offsets from the solar panels because any reduction in the amount of emissions was likely to occur anyway.

2) Measurable Emissions Reductions:

In light of the above, and in order to determine the precise nature and cost of a transaction, the emissions reductions or offsets must not only be additional, but they must be capable of being measured so that the exact amount can be ascertained.

3) Anthropogenic Emissions:

The emissions or emissions reductions must generally be related in some way to human activity (called ‘anthropogenic’), rather than simply being naturally occurring emissions or emissions reductions.

4) Age of the Forest or Plantation:

In the case of carbon sequestration activities (where greenhouse gas emissions are offset by an amount of carbon dioxide stored in a designated forest or plantation), the forest must usually have been planted after 1989 or some other year as designated in the agreement or rules of the trading scheme.

5) Expiration of Forest Credits:

There is sometimes a concern about the ‘nonpermanent’ nature of credits from forest-related activities - in particular, a concern that carbon dioxide offset or stored through forestry activities may not be permanent if the trees in the forest die, are burnt down or are cleared. Because of this concern, forestry-related credits may sometimes be time bound, which means that they exist for only five, 20 or 30 years, after which time they expire. In this case, the agreement may provide that the expired credits must be renewed or replaced at the end of the time period.

6) Sustainable Development:

The proposed activity should contribute to the ‘sustainable development’ of the community with in which it operates. This means that it should form a part of the wider economic, social and environmental development of the community and avoid other detrimental consequences.

Planning for a Project

Before signing an agreement, the project developer or seller of the credits will usually document a clear plan that sets out: what the project will involve; how the emissions reductions or offsets will be measured and certified; the relevant actors and stakeholders; how all stakeholders have been consulted; and what are likely to be the environmental and other impacts and risks of the project. Here are some issues to think about when developing a project plan.

1) Measuring Emissions Reductions:

For the purposes of measuring the precise amount of emissions reductions that result from any funded project (and so as to ensure that there is additionality), it is important to know the quantity of greenhouse gases already being emitted from a targeted activity, and to be able to continue measuring emissions from that activity after the project is implemented.

2) Methodology for Measuring Emissions Reductions:

There are a range of existing ‘methodologies’ for measuring the emissions that result from various daily and commercial activities. There are also organisations, government and scientific, that may be able to help communities to measure the emissions resulting from any single activity, so communities may not have to face this issue alone. Often, assistance from a partner organisation with measuring emissions will itself be a part of the funded emissions reducing project. So while this is a technical point, it does not have to be an insurmountable barrier to involvement in emissions reduction projects.

3) Wider Impact of Project:

In planning for an emissions reducing activity, it is important to consider what wider impacts the project may have on the community and its environment, both good and bad, and to try to ascertain if the project will help the sustainable development of the community.

4) Consultation:

It is important that all relevant stakeholders and community representatives are consulted during the planning of a project. Often times, the buyer and/or any third party financer of an emissions reducing project will seek an assurance that the local community has been consulted and is supportive of the project. Similarly, the local community and/or seller might wish to ensure that the potential buyer is acceptable to them.

5) Right to Emissions Reductions:

When a proposed activity, particularly forestry or land activities, are to take place on land that is not owned by the project developer, it may be necessary to clarify beforehand who would own the legal property rights to any emissions reduction credits or offsets generated. The same applies if the project developer owns the trees on the land, but not the land itself.

6) Verification/certification of Emissions Reductions:

An authorised third party may need to ‘verify’ and ‘certify’ the emissions reductions or offsets.Often times the scheme or agreement under which the activity is taking place will designate  who is entitled to carry out these procedures. In the case of transactions under regulatory schemes, these and many other issues will be decided upon by the rules of the scheme itself. For more information on the precise legal and regulatory issues associated with projects under the Kyoto Protocol’s Clean Development Mechanism.

Examples of Key Regulatory Markets

The Kyoto Protocol allows for several ‘market based mechanisms’ to assist developed countries

(Annex I parties) to meet their emissions reduction targets. ‘Joint Implementation’ allows a developed country to fund and/or run a project to reduce emissions in another developed country. The funding country can then apply the emissions reductions generated to help it to meet its own Kyoto target. Through the ‘Clean Development Mechanism’ (or ‘CDM’), developed countries may finance emissions reducing projects in developing countries that are party to the Kyoto Protocol then use the resulting ‘certified emissions reductions’ (‘CERs’) to offset their own emissions. This mechanism is design to support the sustainable development objectives of developing countries and to provide for the transfer of technology to, and capacity building in, developing countries. It is a very big part of the carbon market, being worth 12 billion Euros in 2007 - an increase in 200% from 2006 and comprising 29% (in financial terms) of the overall market. In reality, views are mixed about whether the CDM has really helped to further sustainable development and technology transfer in developing countries in a substantive way. Many Indigenous communities in particular are concerned about the potentially negative impacts of CDM related activities on their lands and livelihoods.This applies largely to Indigenous communities in developing countries not developed countries - as all CDM projects are hosted in developing countries. Types of CDM projects include: renewable energy, fuel switching (from oil, gas or diesel to gas or biofuels), projects to capture greenhouse gases released from landfill sites; energy efficiency projects; activities to reduce methane from agricultural processes and forestry-related projects, among others. The Kyoto Protocol is also flexible in that developed countries may decide how to reduce their emissions at a domestic level. In this context, a range of emissions trading schemes and other market-based mechanisms have emerged. Examples include the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme, the Swiss Emissions Trading Scheme, the New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme and another scheme running in several North Eastern states of the United States. The US federal government, the state of California, Japan, Canada and Australia among others, are also now in the process of (separately) considering the establishment of such schemes.

The features of each of these schemes are different. In most (but not all) cases, the government places a ‘cap’ on the amount of greenhouse gases that certain factories or companies can emit over a period of several years. These companies are usually from sectors of the economy that emit a lot of greenhouse gases - like heavy industry and power generation. If a company is going to emit more emissions than its cap, it can buy extra credits from another company that has managed to beat its cap (by reducing its emissions below its cap). Another way that companies can comply is to pay to offset their excess emissions through emissions reductions activities undertaken by others. This is where Indigenous communities may most likely play

a role - through providing offsets, particularly through land management or forestry-related activities. The government entity administering the scheme will decide which activities can qualify as potential offsetting activities. Indigenous communities may often also be able to undertake similar activities through the voluntary market.

Carbon Financing Opportunities

Another key aspect of the overall development of efforts to reduce greenhouse gas emissions has been the emergence of a range of opportunities for indirect or third-party financing of emissions reduction activities. This is sometimes referred to as ‘carbon financing’. In fact, it may also include other fiscal incentives, such as tax rebates or exemptions for the installation of emissions reducing equipment, such as solar water panels. International organisations like the World Bank, the Asian Development Bank and the United Nations Development Programme, among others have established a range of funds and programmes to facilitate the creation of emissions reducing activities. These programmes generally focus on emissions reducing activities in developing countries, such that little of this international finance is currently available to Indigenous peoples in developed countries. However, financing opportunities may well exist for Indigenous communities in developed countries, through domestic grant programmes. The reduction of emissions might be just one aspect of a project designed to ensure sustainable land management, ecosystem protection, improved community health, the creation of employment or training opportunities, sustainable livestock management, or the development of a more stable community power supply, for example. When carrying out wider projects like these, it might often be worth considering whether they might have an emissions reducing component and whether that might assist with the attraction of finance.

 Impacts of Carbon Mitigation Activities on Indigenous People

Reports are mixed as to whether climate change mitigation activities are having a positive impact

on the lives and lands of Indigenous peoples. Research suggests that problems can arise when

Indigenous people are not properly consulted, nor their interests taken into account, in the development of carbon mitigation activities. There have been claims of some Indigenous people being evicted from lands to allow for the planting of trees or biofuel crops, or for the development of hydropower schemes, for example. Other commentators note that the growing demand for biofuel crops (for transporation fuel) may reduce the production of food crops and raise food prices. If instituted appropriately, climate change mitigation activities can facilitate the availability and reliability of energy, sound water resource management, a reduction in air pollution and the conservation of ecosystems, plants, animals and land of importance to Indigenous people.

Climate change mitigation activities may encourage a return to country, provide local employment or even encourage the maintenance of traditional practices, such as customary land management activities. Additionally, it is important to bear in mind that Indigenous people themselves can contribute a great deal to mitigating and adapting to climate change, given their experiences of responding to natural climatic change over millennia and given their ownership of considerable tracts of forested and wild land.

Friday, 18 October 2013

LIST OF NOBEL LAUREATES IN ECONOMICS




List of Nobel Memorial Prize laureates in Economics

Collected by Dr.Debesh Bhowmik 
 
The Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences, officially known as The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel (Swedish: Sveriges riksbanks pris i ekonomisk vetenskap till Alfred Nobels minne), is awarded annually by the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences to researchers in the field of economics. Although not one of the original five Nobel Prizes established by the 1895 will of Alfred Nobel, it is consistently identified with them. The award was established and funded in 1968 by the Sveriges Riksbank, the central bank of Sweden, on the 300th anniversary of the bank, and has been awarded annually since. The first award was given in 1969 to Ragnar Frisch and Jan Tinbergen. Each recipient receives a medal, a diploma and a monetary award that has varied throughout the years. In 1969, Frisch and Tinbergen were given a combined 375,000 SEK, which is equivalent to 2,871,041 SEK in December 2007. The award is presented in Stockholm at an annual ceremony on December 10, the anniversary of Nobel's death.
As of late 2013, 45 Nobel Memorial Prizes in Economic Sciences have been given to 74 individuals. Seven awards have been given for contributions to the field of macroeconomics, more than any other category. The institution with the most affiliated Nobel laureates in Economics is the University of Chicago, which has 28 affiliated laureates.
Laureates
Paul Samuelson.gif
Year
Laureate
Country
Rationale
1969

Norway
"for having developed and applied dynamic models for the analysis of economic processes"
Netherlands
1970
United States
"for the scientific work through which he has developed static and dynamic economic theory and actively contributed to raising the level of analysis in economic science"
1971
Kuznets portrait.jpg
United States
"for his empirically founded interpretation of economic growth which has led to new and deepened insight into the economic and social structure and process of development"
1972

United Kingdom
"for their pioneering contributions to general economic equilibrium theory and welfare theory."
United States
1973

Soviet Union
"for the development of the input-output method and for its application to important economic problems"
1974
Sweden
"for their pioneering work in the theory of money and economic fluctuations and for their penetrating analysis of the interdependence of economic, social and institutional phenomena."

United Kingdom / Austria
1975
"for their contributions to the theory of optimum allocation of resources"

United States / Netherlands
1976
United States
"for his achievements in the fields of consumption analysis, monetary history and theory and for his demonstration of the complexity of stabilisation policy"
1977
Sweden
"for their pathbreaking contribution to the theory of international trade and international capital movements"
James Meade Nobel.jpg
United Kingdom
1978

United States
"for his pioneering research into the decision-making process within economic organizations"
1979

United States
"for their pioneering research into economic development research with particular consideration of the problems of developing countries."

United Kingdom
1980

United States
"for the creation of econometric models and the application to the analysis of economic fluctuations and economic policies"
1981

United States
"for his analysis of financial markets and their relations to expenditure decisions, employment, production and prices"
1982

United States
"for his seminal studies of industrial structures, functioning of markets and causes and effects of public regulation"
1983
France
"for having incorporated new analytical methods into economic theory and for his rigorous reformulation of the theory of general equilibrium"
1984

United Kingdom
"for having made fundamental contributions to the development of systems of national accounts and hence greatly improved the basis for empirical economic analysis"
1985
Italy
"for his pioneering analyses of saving and of financial markets"
1986
United States
"for his development of the contractual and constitutional bases for the theory of economic and political decision-making"
1987
United States
"for his contributions to the theory of economic growth"
1988
France
"for his pioneering contributions to the theory of markets and efficient utilization of resources"
1989
Norway
"for his clarification of the probability theory foundations of econometrics and his analyses of simultaneous economic structures"
1990

United States
"for their pioneering work in the theory of financial economics"

United States
United States
1991

United Kingdom
"for his discovery and clarification of the significance of transaction costs and property rights for the institutional structure and functioning of the economy"
1992
United States
"for having extended the domain of microeconomic analysis to a wide range of human behaviour and interaction, including non-market behaviour"
1993
United States
"for having renewed research in economic history by applying economic theory and quantitative methods in order to explain economic and institutional change"

United States
1994

United States
"for their pioneering analysis of equilibria in the theory of non-cooperative games."
United States
Germany
1995

United States
"for having developed and applied the hypothesis of rational expectations, and thereby having transformed macroeconomic analysis and deepened our understanding of economic policy"
1996

United Kingdom
"for their fundamental contributions to the economic theory of incentives under asymmetric information"

United States / Canada
1997
United States
"for a new method to determine the value of derivatives."
Canada / United States
1998
India
1999
Canada
"for his analysis of monetary and fiscal policy under different exchange rate regimes and his analysis of optimum currency areas"
2000
United States
"for his development of theory and methods for analyzing selective samples"
United States
"for his development of theory and methods for analyzing discrete choice"
2001
United States
"for their analyses of markets with asymmetric information"
United States
United States
2002
Israel / United States
"for having integrated insights from psychological research into economic science, especially concerning human judgment and decision-making under uncertainty"
United States
"for having established laboratory experiments as a tool in empirical economic analysis, especially in the study of alternative market mechanisms"
2003
United States
"for methods of analyzing economic time series with time-varying volatility (ARCH)"
United Kingdom
"for methods of analyzing economic time series with common trends (cointegration)"
2004
Norway
"for their contributions to dynamic macroeconomics: the time consistency of economic policy and the driving forces behind business cycles."
United States
2005
Israel / United States
"for having enhanced our understanding of conflict and cooperation through game-theory analysis."
United States
2006
United States
"for his analysis of intertemporal tradeoffs in macroeconomic policy"
2007
Poland / United States
"for having laid the foundations of mechanism design theory"
United States
United States
2008
United States
"for his analysis of trade patterns and location of economic activity"
2009
United States
"for her analysis of economic governance, especially the commons"
United States
"for his analysis of economic governance, especially the boundaries of the firm"
2010
United States
"for their analysis of markets with search frictions"
United States
2011
United States
"for their empirical research on cause and effect in the macroeconomy"
United States
2012
United States
"for the theory of stable allocations and the practice of market design."
United States
2013

United States
"for their empirical analysis of asset prices."
United States
United States