IJSRP, Volume 7, Issue 2, February 2017 Edition [ISSN 2250-3153]
Dr.Debesh Bhowmik
Abstract: The paper studied the behavior of total retail sales of ecommerce in India during 2005-2020 with the help of semilog and exponential trend model and Bai-Perron(2003) test for structural shift and Hodrick-Prescott Filter (1989) model for smooth trend and ARIMA(1,1,1) model for stationary and we relates its relationship with internet users,credit and debit card users and GDP growth rate during 2005-2015 with the help of double log multivariable regression model although Johansen cointegration test(1988) and VEC model(1996)were applied to relate growth with retail sales of ecommerce. ...............
link for download
http://www.ijsrp.org/research-php-0217.php?rp=p626175
India’s
Retail Sales of ECommerce: An Econometric Analysis
Dr.Debesh
Bhowmik
(Retired
Principal,Associate Editor-Arthabeekshan-Journal of Bengal Economic
Association)
Abstract
The paper studied the behavior of total retail sales
of ecommerce in India during 2005-2020 with the help of semilog and exponential
trend model and Bai-Perron(2003) test for structural shift and Hodrick-Prescott
Filter (1989) model for smooth trend and ARIMA(1,1,1) model for stationary and
we relates its relationship with internet users,credit and debit card users and
GDP growth rate during 2005-2015 with the help of double log multivariable
regression model although Johansen
cointegration test(1988) and VEC model(1996)were applied to relate growth with
retail sales of ecommerce.
The paper found out those retail sales of ecommerce
in India during 2005-2020 has been increasing at the rate 41.93% per year which
is significant and it is exponentially increases at the rate of 0.728% per year
which is more acceptable and significant whose residual test confirmed that
exponential series has heteroscedasticity , autocorrelation ,partial
autocorrelation and serial correlation
problems. The retail sales of ecommerce in India during 2005-2020 do not follow
random walk and random walk with drift which is strengthened by variance ratio
test but it consists of three upward structural breaks in 2007,2010 and in
2013.Yet it is turned into smooth trend line from cyclical path by H.P.Filter
model. But its ARIMA(1,1,1) model showed the series is unstable and
nonstationary.
The paper also showed that one percent hike in
percent of population of internet users led to 1.931% increase in retail sales
in ecommerce during 2005-2015 in India which is significant at 1% level. Besides,
one percent increase in debit card users and GDP growth rate led to 1.267%
increase and 1.768% decrease in retail sales in ecommerce significantly but it
has insignificant positive relation with credit card users. When growth is
dependent variable ,then growth and debit card users are significantly positively
associated but when retail sales is dependent variable then internet users and
retail sales are positively associated significantly. Granger Causality test
confirmed that total retail sales in ecommerce(x1) ,percent of
population using internet(x2), number of credit (x3)and
debit cards(x4),GDP growth rate of India (y) during 2005-2020 showed
bidirectional causality except X2 does not Granger Cause X1and x2 and x4 have no
causality. Johansen cointegration test assures that GDP growth rate and retail
sales in ecommerce are cointegrated in the order CI(1) in which VEC model is
unstable, diverging and error correction
is speedy and significant in the equation Δyt.
The paper states that Ecommerce in India grew so
fast that it ranks second preceded by China and it may constitute 4% of GDP
within 2020 where India needs improved infrastructure,control fraud e payment
and e security, develop e-Customs and
e-taxation,minimize regulatory gap,and many others policies recommended by
several institutions.
Key
words- retail sales of ecommerce, internet users, credit and debit card users,
GDP growth rate, structural break, Granger-Causality, cointegration , VECM
JEL-C32,M21,M31,M48
I.Introduction
E-commerce ─ broadly defined as
the use of the Internet as a platform for sales, sourcing, and exchange of
market information ─ is playing an important role in supporting global economic
growth. Latest market research data predicts that the share of e-commerce of
total sales will reach 12.4% in 2019.
Industry surveys suggest that e-commerce industry is expected to
contribute around 4 percent to the GDP by 2020. In comparison, according to a
NASSCOM report, by 2020, the IT-BPO industry is expected to account for 10% of
India’s GDP, while the
share of telecommunication services in India’s GDP is expected to increase to 15 percent by 2015.
With enabling support, the e-commerce industry too can contribute much more to
the GDP. Around 90% of the global
e-commerce transactions are stated to be in the nature of B2B, leaving meagre
10% as B2C e-commerce. Case of India is no different where most of such
transactions are in the nature of B2B. Moreover Indian e-commerce industry is
characterized by “Market Place” model. McKinsey Global Institute
estimated that the Internet contributes an average 3.4 percent in developed
countries and 1.9 percent of GDP in aspiring countries. In some aspiring
countries, such as Taiwan and Malaysia, the Internet contributes to GDP at
levels similar to those in developed countries. This is due to their strong net
exports of ICT goods and services. In line with other aspiring countries, the
Internet’s contribution to India’s GDP
— what we call its iGDP — is
moderate today, at 1.6 percent, or $30 billion in GDP. At 1.6 percent of GDP,
India’s iGDP is comparable in size to key service sectors, such as hotels and
restaurants, and utilities.India’s share of Internet-linked GDP at about 3.2
percent.Even in 2015, when aggregate Internet penetration is projected to reach
28 percent, the penetration of India’s rural population is likely to remain at
a low 9 percent, compared with urban penetration of 64 percent. India’s likely
Internet penetration of 28 percent in 2015 will be far less than the projected
global average of 43 percent. To achieve a penetration of nearly 40 percent by
2015, which would be similar to China’s Internet penetration at that date,
India would need to have notched up more than 500 million Internet users.
Institute’s projections indicate that by 2015 India is likely to have a base of
more than 100 million Internet-enabled smart devices and more than 150 million
consumers with low cost, high speed Internet access. By 2015, India’s 330
million to 370 million projected Internet users will constitute an estimated 12
to 13 percent of the global Internet user base, the second-largest national
group of Internet users worldwide behind only China. If India puts itself on an
accelerated trajectory towards higher penetration to reach 500 million Internet
users by 2015, the iGDP could be as high as 3.3 percent.
Global Retail Development
Index-2016 showed that China ranks one in this index followed by India. China
scored 72.5 where as India scored 71.0.Chinese national retail sale stood 3.46
billion US dollar followed by 1009 billion US dollar of India. A.T. Kearney’s
2016 FDI Confidence Index ranks China second-a signal of its continued
attractions to foreign investors.GDP growth improved case of doing business and
better clarity regarding FDI regulations puts India in second place. India is
now the world’s fastest growing major economy overtaking China. Retail demand
is increasing driven by urbanization, an expanding middle class and more women
entering the workforce. India’s strong ranking reflects foreign retailer
increased optimum in the 1 trillion US Dollar retail market and its vast
potential. In ecommerce, government now permits 100% FDI for on line market
places, with some caveats to create a level playing field.
In this paper, we endeavour to
show the behavior of total retail sales of ecommerce during 2005-2020 and its
nexus with internet users,credit and debit card users and GDP growth rate of
India during 2005-2015
....................
The paper concludes that retail sales of ecommerce
in India during 2005-2020 has been increasing at the rate 41.93% per year which
is significant and it is exponentially increases at the rate of 0.728% per year
which is more acceptable and significant whose residual test confirmed that
exponential series has heteroscedasticity ,autocorrelation ,partial
autocorrelation and serial correlation
problems. The retail sales of ecommerce in India during 2005-2020 do not follow
random walk and random walk with drift which is strengthened by variance ratio
test but it consists of three upward structural breaks in 2007,2010 and 2013.Yet
it is turned into smooth trend line from cyclical path by H.P.Filter model. But
its ARIMA(1,1,1) model showed the series is unstable and nonstationary.
The paper also concludes that one percent hike in
percent of population in internet users led to 1.931% increase in retail sales
in ecommerce during 2005-2015 in India which is significant at 1% level. Besides,
one percent increase in debit card users and GDP growth rate led to 1.267%
increase and 1.768% decrease in retail sales in ecommerce significantly but it
has insignificant positive relation with credit card users. When growth is
dependent variable ,then growth and debit card users are significantly
positively associated but when retail sales is dependent variable then internet
users and retail sales are positively associated significantly. Granger Causality test confirmed that total retail sales
in ecommerce(x1) ,percent of population using internet(x2),
number of credit (x3)and debit cards(x4),GDP growth rate
of India (y) during 2005-2020 showed bidirectional causality except X2
does not Granger Cause X1and
x2 and x4 have no causality. Johansen
cointegration test assures that GDP growth rate and retail sales in ecommerce
are cointegrated in the order CI(1) in which VEC model is unstable, diverging and error correction is speedy and
significant in the equation Δyt.
The paper states that Ecommerce in India grew so
fast that it ranks second preceded by China and it may constitute 4% of GDP
within 2020 where India needs improved infrastructure, control fraud e payment
and e security, develop e-customs and
e-taxation, minimize regulatory gap, and many others policies recommended by
several institutions.
References
APEC Business Advisory
Council,2015,
Driving
Economic Growth Through Cross-Border
E-Commerce in APEC: Empowering
MSMEs and Eliminating Barriers, University of Southern California, Marshall
School of Business, November
Bai,Jushan
and Pierre Perron.,2003,Critical values for multiple structural change tests, Econometrics Journal,Volume-6,72-78
Elseoud,
Mohamed Sayed.,2014, Electronic Commerce And Economic Growth In Saudi Arabia, International Journal of Economics, Commerce
and Management ,United
Kingdom Vol. II, Issue 5,
Enders,Walter.,2011,Applied Econometric Time Series. Wiley
Student Edition.
Global Express Association,2016, Cross-border E-commerce – Engine for Growth Suggestions for Enabling
Growth, Position paper, January.
read from
www.ijsrp.org
| International Journal of Scientific and Research Publications |
Dr.DEBESH BHOWMIK
Tuesday, 7 February 2017
India’s Retail Sales of ECommerce: An Econometric Analysis
Sunday, 5 February 2017
CARBON TRADING AND INDIA'S ROAD MAP
CARBON TRADING AND INDIA'S ROAD MAP
---Dr.Debesh Bhowmik
INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF ENVIRONMENT,AGRICULTURE AND BIO-TECHNOLOGY
----VOL-2,ISSUE-1,JANUARY-FEBRUARY ,2017,118-126
-----www.ijeab.com
CARBON
TRADING AND INDIA’S ROAD MAP
Dr.Debesh
Bhowmik(Retired principal and Former Associate Editor-Arthabeekshan-the journal
of Bengal Economic Association)
Abstract
In this article, the
author describes the concept of carbon trading , its global market ,mechanism
of global trading, international organization, EUETS, relationship between REDD and carbon market in relation with
agreements of Paris convention. The 10 myths of REDD+ and carbon market are
additional features which can explore future research. The paper highlighted
India’s roadmap for carbon market potentiality in 2020.
Key
words – carbon trading, global carbon market, REDD, India’s road map
JEL-F18,O44,Q56
I.What is Carbon Trading
Carbon
trading is the buying and selling of a new, artificially-created commodity –
the right to emit carbon dioxide. Unlike trading in other commodities like
crude oil or bananas, carbon trading is not a voluntary exchange between
producers and those who want to consume or sell on the goods. Instead, it
results from action by governments to create this new commodity – the right to
emit carbon – and then to limit the availability of this right in order to
create scarcity and therefore a market for it.
Carbon
trading is one of a number of different approaches that have been developed and
adopted by governments as a means of controlling the amount of carbon dioxide
that is emitted into the atmosphere and reducing this amount over time. It is
based on the broader approach, purportedly to control the emission of
pollutants, known as ‘cap and trade’.
Cap and trade is often referred
to as a market-based mechanism and contrasted with a different set of tools
available to governments to influence behaviours, those which come under the
umbrella of direct regulation or standard setting. However, this contrasting of
market-based and non-market-based approach is sometimes unhelpful. It ignores
the fact that market mechanisms do not operate in a vacuum. Instead, they
always take place in a social and economic environment underpinned by various
government laws and regulations and often require these laws in order to be
effective. Carbon trading is a case in point. Carbon markets are directly
created by government regulation.
Perhaps
a more useful distinction for the purposes of this report is that between
direct and indirect mechanisms. Carbon trading can be classed as an indirect
tool as it is supposed to achieve its purpose of reducing emissions indirectly
by affecting the price of those emissions. This in turn affects the behaviour
of ‘actors’ in the market, i.e. those responsible for producing the emissions,
by creating an incentive for them to save money by reducing their emissions and
hence change their behaviour. In contrast, government regulation and standard
setting are direct interventions to change behaviour, not reliant on
intermediate mechanisms such as prices. Taxation is an indirect mechanism as it
aims to change behaviour through affecting the price of a good, service or
activity. However, it is arguably less indirect than trading as governments fix
the price with a tax whereas with trading the price is determined by the
market.
The carbon trade is an idea that came about in
response to the Kyoto Protocol. The Kyoto Protocol is an agreement under which
industrialized countries will reduce their greenhouse gas emissions between the
years 2008 to 2012 to levels that are 5.2% lower than those of 1990.
The idea behind carbon trading is quite similar to the
trading of securities or commodities in a market place. Carbon would be given
an economic value, allowing people, companies or nations to trade it. If a
nation bought carbon, it would be buying the rights to burn it, and a nation
selling carbon would be giving up its rights to burn it. The value of the
carbon would be based on the ability of the country owning the carbon to store
it or to prevent it from being released into the atmosphere. A market would be
created to facilitate the buying and selling of the rights to emit greenhouse
gases. The industrialized nations for which reducing emissions is a daunting
task could buy the emission rights from another nation whose industries do not
produce as much of these gases. The market for carbon is possible because the
goal of the Kyoto Protocol is to reduce emissions as a collective.
On
the one hand, the idea of carbon trade seems like a win-win situation:
greenhouse gas emissions may be reduced while some countries reap economic
benefit. On the other hand, critics of the idea suspect that some countries
will exploit the trading system and the consequences will be negative. While
the proposal of carbon trade does have its merits, debate over this type of
market is inevitable since it involves finding a compromise between profit,
equality and ecological concerns.
The carbon market is one of the most effective policies
for tackling climate change. It inspires operational excellence and incentivizes
business investments in low-carbon technologies. Not only is the market expected
to save over 2 billion tones of CO2 emissions by the end of 2012,
but the development of the current global carbon market, now worth over US$140
billion, has catapulted climate change to the forefront of business decisions. But
while it exhibits real environmental and economic impact, and helps achieve
climate change goals, it remains vulnerable to external factors.
The Harnessing
demand for Indian projects post-2012 are :
1.
Supporting
projects through domestic emission trading scheme –
2.
Supporting projects through NCEF and CSR
funds of large companies
3.
Developing standardized baselines
4.
Developing sustainable development impact
reporting
5.Evaluating and
highlighting the benefits of CDM projects focusing on sustainable development Impacts
6. Constituting
a high level Multi Stakeholder Advisory Group for Climate Change issues
like Loss and Damage,
Equity, Sustainable Development, Gender etc
7. Developing NAMAs
8. Developing
the capacity for national emission reduction reporting and develop credible
and robust reporting
frameworks for corporate carbon reporting–
But there are several
causes of delays of maturing projects which are as follows:
[i]
One
of the major reasons for delays in registration of CDM projects is on account
of lack of acceptable guidelines for setting benchmark, lack of institutional
capacity, frequent revisions to CDM EB guidelines and lengthy validation cycle
[ii]
The
delay in registration of CDM projects was due to the increase in CDM projects from
India and limited increase in the number of DOEs
[iii]
The
cement and energy efficiency project-types have higher rejection rate than hydro
and wind project-types
[iv]Projects in reforestation, EE household,
EE in SME, off-grid solar and agriculture project-types face MRV, organizational
and financial barriers.
[v]
HFC
23, N2O and landfill gas(where these is no energy generation) projects risk closure
post the withdrawal of market support and fall in CER prices
[vi]
Goa,
Bihar, Jharkhand, Kerala, Jammu & Kashmir, Haryana and North Eastern states
have very limited development of CDM projects
The promotion
and development of the emission reduction projects will require a combination
of the following measures:
[i]
Demand-side
measures: Given the weak demand for CERs and the uncertain time frame for new
market mechanisms, all attempts should be made to revive demand in the existing
regulatory framework, particularly for projects registered post 2012.
[ii]
Improving
sustainable development impacts: Improving the sustainable development impacts
as well as
improving communication on the outcomes / impacts of CDM project activities is
required for stimulating demand of quality CDM projects and addressing
international concerns.
[iii]
Efficiency
of registration: Once there is a revival of demand, measures should be
undertaken
to remove the
barriers in CDM project registration while also improving sustainable development
impacts.
[iv]
Future
regulatory mechanisms: Recognizing that CDM is likely to be transitory in
nature
and new market mechanisms
are likely to be more prominent particularly in the post 2020
carbon markets,
measures should be undertaken to develop synergies between CDM, NAMAs
and other market
mechanisms.
[v]
Supply
side measures: Once there is regulatory certainty and robust demand, supply
side
measures should
be undertaken that encourage larger participation of industry in emerging
global carbon / CDM
market.
Therefore, the
recommendations below are targeted towards:
A. Harnessing
demand for Indian projects post 2012;
B. Achieving
better sustainable development for CDM projects;
C. Developing
synergies between CDM, NAMAs and other market mechanisms; and
D. Encouraging larger
participation of industry in carbon market.
IX.Concluding Remarks
The
international carbon market currently faces considerable uncertainties
regarding its future architecture. There are a number of options for further
development,including a global trading approach building on Kyoto, formal
linkages of domestic ETS leading to a global CO2 market, and indirect linkages
through credits if domestic ETS remain otherwise unconnected. Also, a mixed
approach is conceivable. Regions should share a common understanding on the
overall
climate policy
goal (e.g., the 2°C target) as well as a burden-sharing rule translating into
ETS caps. These two fundamental issues will crucially determine the level of
ambition of an ETS as expressed in (a) the emission cap, which in combination
with amount and costs of available abatement options of a region crucially
determines the allowance price level; and (b) ETS design features also exerting
influence on the allowance price level and environmental outcome. For a player
with ambitious environmental targets it should be preferable to announce that
it will link only under the condition that another system displays a similar
level of ambition, thus using the
efficiency and
potential reputational benefits from linking as a bargaining chip. Linking to
less ambitious regions would undermine the credibility of such announcements.
Harmonization of trading systems should start as early as possible in order to
enable the option of linking ETS post-2012. For this purpose, ICAP could be a
nucleus for such an international clearinghouse.
References
[1]Angelsen,Arid.,Gierloff,Caroline
Wang ,Beltran,Angelica Mendoza & Elzen,Michel den . (2014).REDD Credits in
a global carbon market:Options and Impacts.NORDEN.
[2]Anger, N.,
Dixon,A & Livengood,E.(2009). Interactions
of Reduced Deforestation and the Carbon Market. The Role of Market Regulations and
Future Commitments.Center for European Economic Research: Discussion Paper No. 09–001.
[3]Baron, R.&
Bygrave,S.(2002). Towards International Emissions Trading: Design
implications
for linkages. IEA/OECD Paper
[4]Bhowmik,Debesh.(2017).An
Introduction to Climate Change,Synergy Books India Ltd, NewDelhi.
[5]Deutsche
Gesellschaft fur Internationale Zusammenarbeit.(2014,January).Carbon Market
Road Map for India,BMUB Global Carbon Market Project,NewDelhi.
[6]Edenhofer,
Ottmar, Flachsland,Christian & Marschinski,Robert.(2007,May). Towards a
global CO2 market. Expertise for the Policy Planning Staff in the
Federal Foreign Office. Potsdam Institute for Climate Impact Research.
[7]Ellermann, Denny.(2012).
Linking Emissions Trading Schemes: Back to the Basics; paper presented on 12
November 2012 at the ZEW Conference “Rise of ETS in Asia”
[8]Ellis, J.&Tirpak,D.(2006).
Linking GHG Emission Trading Systems and Markets.
IEA/OECD
Paper.
[9]German
Emission Trading Authority.(2013).Linking Different Emissions Trading System: Current
State and Future Perspectives,Berlin.
[10]Hausotter, Tobias.,Sibyl,Steuer
& Dennis,Tanzler.( 2011). Competitiveness and Linking of Emission Trading
Systems (UBA Climate Change 01/2011) http://www.umweltdaten.de/publikationen/fpdf-l/4051.pdf
[11]Karsenty,A.(2009).‘What
the (carbon) market cannot do.’ CIRARD.
http://www.cirad.fr/en/news/all-news-items/articles/2009/just-out/perspective
[12]Moyes, T.E.(2008).
Greenhouse gas emission trading in New
Zealand: Trailblazing
comprehensive cap and trade. Ecology
L.Q. 911
[13]Murray, B.
C., Lubowski,R & Sohngen,B. (2009). Including International Forest
Carbon
Incentives in Climate
Policy:
Understanding the Economics. Nicholas Institute Report. Durham, NC: Nicholas Institute
for Environmental Policy Solutions, Duke University.
[14]Pirard, R.(2008).
‘The fight against deforestation (REDD+): economic implications of market-based
funding.’ Paris: IDDRI.
[15]Pizer,
William.(2007). Practical Global Climate Policy. In: Aldy, Joseph E., and
Robert
N.
Stavins (2007): Architectures for
Agreement. Addressing Global Climate Change in the Post-Kyoto World.
Cambridge University Press
[16]Potsdam Institute
for Climate Impact Research.(2008).Developing the International Carbon
Market:Linking Options for EUETS,NZ
[17]Tangen,
Kristian & Hasselknippe,Henrik.(2005,March).Converging
Markets.International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics. Volume 5, No 1.
[18]The Carbon Trust.(2008).
Global Carbon Mechanisms: emerging lessons and implications. UK: Carbon Trust,
p. 11.
[19]The Munden Project.(2011).REDD+
and forest carbon. http://www.mundenproject.com/
forestcarbonreport2.pdf
[20]The RAIN FOREST
FOUNDATION.(2011,June).REDD+ and Carbon
Market:10 Myths exploded,Green peace.
[21]UNEP.(2010).
Bringing forest carbon projects to the market, New York.
[22]UNFCCC.(2010b).
Quantified economy-wide emission targets for 2020- Appendix I.
Available from http://unfccc.int/home/items/5264.php
[23]Victor,
David.(2007). Fragmented carbon markets and reluctant nations: implications for
the
design of effective architectures. In:Aldy, Joseph E., and Robert N. Stavins (2007):
Architectures for Agreement. Addressing
Global Climate Change in the Post-Kyoto World. Cambridge University Press
[24]World Bank .(2011,June).
State and Trends of the Carbon Market 2011. Carbon Finance at
the World Bank,
Washington DC.
[25]Zetterberg, Lars.(
2012). Linking the Emissions Trading Systems in EU and California, Fores, Stockholm http://fores.se/assets/780/FORES-California_ETS-web.pdf
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)